The past year has made quite a difference in the lowest
hourly amount American workers can legally be paid. Before it, we were hearing about “the fight
for $15,” with implications from those left of center that such a struggle was
not only noble but just. Now those calls
have died down, and that quest doesn’t look worthy, even to many liberals. What has happened to shift the tide?
In “The Minimum Wage Eats Restaurants” (The Wall Street Journal, May 9), marked as “Commentary,” Michael
Saltsman presented data that 60 San Francisco-area eateries closed between
September and January, and cited one owner as saying “there’s only so much you
can charge for tamales.” Saltsman cited
a Harvard and Mathematica study connecting a $1 increase in the minimum wage
with a 14% rise in the chance of a “3.5-star” restaurant folding, and concluded
that better pay and benefits “don’t mean much if you can’t find a job.” In contrast, though, The New York Times editorial board, in “Remember the promise of
good jobs?” on June 13th, while correctly in my view disapproving of
the Fed raising interest rates, the presidential administration seeking to reduce
top-bracket taxes, and the blocking of badly-needed for-inflation adjustments
of mandatory overtime pay thresholds, tripped on issues of average pay not
tracking productivity gains (why should it?), higher minimum wages when over 17
million Americans want to work and can’t find it, and a vain hope for “Republican
leaders’ changing their ways.”
For 16 days in late June and early July, we had what might
be called “dueling studies” on the outcome of Seattle’s minimum wage
increases. Fox Business, in “Study:
Seattle minimum wage hasn’t cut jobs” (June 20), started the ball
rolling, naming a University of California at Berkeley research effort finding
that, without, though, a look at how many additional jobs went uncreated, and citing
a University of Washington effort determining that “the law appeared to have
slightly reduced the employment rate of low-wage workers even as it boosted
pay.” The New York Times also covered
both in Noam Scheiber’s June 26th “How a Rising Minimum Wage Affects
Jobs in Seattle,” concluding that its labor market was unusually strong and
that total earnings by workers in low-paying jobs actually decreased, as did The Seattle Times, in Jon Talton’s nicely
titled June 27th “Seattle’s minimum wage: The plot thickens,” which noted that neither
piece of research had yet been peer reviewed, but did not mention that automated
solutions, which can be stated and sold in terms of the cost of labor being
replaced, can forestall additional positions.
Three days later Holman W. Jenkins Jr. weighed in in The Wall Street Journal, opining that “Seattle
Aims at McDonald’s, Hits Workers.”
Although he lost any claim to objectivity by not even mentioning the
Berkeley study, he made good points, such as that President Obama’s statement “that
a full-time job should be able to support a family,” when implemented through
higher minimums, “was a way of saying that jobs that won’t support a family
shouldn’t exist,” and that many countries allow “teenagers, trainees,” and “probationary
hires” to be paid less. Politically
centrist USA Today, in July 5th’s
“In ‘Fight for $15,’ Seattle loses,” concluded the same, matching Yahoo Finance’s Rick Newman in June 26th’s
“A $15 minimum wage appears to be too high.”
The last straw, though, may have come from generally liberal Washington Post columnist Catherine
Rampell, in “Feel-good ideas that need a hardhearted examination,” who
concluded that a mandatory $15 minimum “would risk pricing a lot of people out
of work,” such as in Mississippi, where half of workers were now paid below
$14.22.
One indication of a trend topping out is people not only
refusing to join it, but rollbacks. Fox News’s June 29th “Maine
restaurant workers successfully lobby to lower the minimum wage” recapped how servers
arranged for defeat of new laws endangering their jobs by forcing employers to
pay them the same minimums as non-tipped workers. An even clearer sign of a tide turning is backlash
reactions, such as the subject of “Missouri Republicans Lower St. Louis Minimum
Wage from $10 to $7.70” (Yahoo.com,
July 3rd), implementation of a state law barring communities there
from setting their own, higher, floors.
That is a questionable step, since one problem with state-level wage
mandates is that they do not account for differing living costs, resulting in
required pay being too high in some areas, too low (if you advocate meaningful minimum
wages) for others, or both, and they prevent local governments from making decisions
that should fall to them.
In the context of the fight for $15 being seemingly on the
way out, we probably won’t need to worry about something being assessed in the
United Kingdom, a “Minimum wage push for gig economy workers” (Kamal Ahmed, bbc.com, July 10th). That is a good thing, since, in addition to
removing this bottom rung on the ladder, such would require either determining
maximum lengths of time these tasks would take or paying less effective workers
more to complete them. I do like the
idea of officially designating them “dependent contractors,” between employees
and independent agents, which while not as good as making them the same as
company-hired would remove the pretense that they are free to work any way they
want. Yet they cannot viably have
guaranteed hourly rates. That would be bad
– and, as I also believe that about higher national minimum wages, the shift in
our views is positive.
No comments:
Post a Comment