It’s strange to realize that most people in this country have never experienced price increases of more than 4% annually, but that’s correct. We have not seen inflation as high as the annual 7% the Bureau of Labor Statistics announced Wednesday since 1981. Accordingly, many can’t be counted on to understand it. So here’s more.
It exceeds the money things cost, as pointed out by Neil
Irwin in “There Is Shadow Inflation Taking Place All Around Us,” revised
October 11th in The New York Times. The author was writing about reductions in
service which aren’t counted in tabulations of price increases, such as rarer
cleaning of restaurants and hotel rooms and slower and less comprehensive
product availability.
If you think prices will increase more slowly soon, Matt
Phillips, on October 26th also in the New York Times, disagreed
with “The Bond Market Says Inflation Will Last.
You Should Be Listening.” Per
Phillips, bond prices can be measured by determining a “break even,” assuming that
their five-year returns equal the projected inflation rate. That reached “about 3 percent a year,” which,
as low as that seems, would be “far higher than any time in the decade before
the pandemic hit.”
Back to Irwin, who, on December 31st and again in
the Times, told us “What We Learned About the Economy in 2021.” One of his four points was “people really,
really, really don’t like inflation.” It
has been a source of “generalized discontent,” and has caused “poorer customer
service,” “more hassle planning Christmas gifts far ahead of time,” and beyond. It is too easy, as Irwin put it, to take
attitudes of “that pay raise was money I earned fair and square” but “that
higher grocery bill is an affront done to my by powerful forces beyond my
control.”
Once more in The New York Times, we had Paul Krugman,
in January 7th’s “Wonking Out:
Through A Price Index, Darkly,” give us some of inflation’s technical
details, along with the sound observations that “economic developments since
the pandemic began have taken place in Covid time – that is, they’ve moved at a
pace that makes past ups and downs look as if they were filmed in slow motion”
and “the one-year rate of change is more or less guaranteed to show continuing high
inflation for a while even if actual price pressures are quickly fading away.” The last, exemplified by the price of
gasoline, is because such statistics show what has happened over the entire
time period, and can conceal recent leveling-off or even dropping.
So what observations can we make about our current price
increases?
First, this is not typical inflation with root causes self-sustaining
and hard to pinpoint. It is due to
temporary supply-chain disruptions cutting supply, higher wages increasing
business costs, and irregular demand from the pandemic’s changes. That means the usual recommended measures may
not be effective or necessary.
Second, the past 40 years notwithstanding, we have had
inflation during much of our history.
Per google.com, the average rate since 1914 has been 3.25 percent, which
means that at times it has been more.
It’s normal.
Third, zeroing in on cutting inflation would mean more
shortages of both goods and workers and higher unemployment, neither of which
is popular either.
No comments:
Post a Comment