A year and a month ago I posted twice about something existing
on a small scale for as long as anyone could remember, but had only recently
been given a name and drawn a flurry of discussion. The “gig economy,” or the offering and
working of individual and often very short tasks or sets of tasks, seemed to be
gaining a new credibility. I commented
that although taking such small-scale employment was clearly an economic
inferior good, it offered both experience and the chance to earn money without
being held off by minimum wage laws.
Since then, it has continued without as much attention – but what has
been said about it when it has reached print?
On June 4th, Jonathon M. Trugman expressed his
displeasure about this phenomenon in New
York Post (“This new ‘gig’ economy isn’t helping anyone”). He didn’t really support the title in the
article, which stated that “temporary gig work is better than no work at all,”
but did tell us, sadly, that the net new number of American temporary positions
added from 2005 to 2015, 9.4 million, exceeded that time’s overall jobs increase, 9.1 million.
That movement away from permanent positions is the real trend, and is
disturbing enough, but hardly means that other opportunities are worthless.
A more balanced view turned up in CNN Money (“Millions in gig economy can’t find better jobs or pay,”
October 27), which acknowledged both the advantages and disadvantages I named
above. The statistics here, apparently
invoked to be negative, almost served the other side better; although “nearly
30% of gig workers who work part-time would prefer a full-time job,” that
number could be much higher, and it is redundant to say that three-quarters of
“these part-timers” have low incomes.
What’s interesting about “Rigging the gig economy: A proposed bill would lure freelance workers
to sign away their employee rights for cash” (Salon, November 29th), is that it sought to make one
politically liberal point, failed, and in the process unintentionally put forth
cases for two others. It related a
proposed legislative bill that would either mandate, or allow participation in,
a scheme where companies would subsidize gig workers’ health care at an amount
equal to 2.5% of their income, in exchange for them agreeing to “accept their
classification as nonemployees.” That’s
not a large bonus, but it is significant, and, if they are legally not on their
companies’ payrolls, it costs them nothing.
The two true improvements it supported were strict, well-enforced worker-favoring
laws on what constitutes a contractor as opposed to an employee, and national
health insurance unconnected to income sources.
It was months later before anything more on this subject
crossed my desk, and it was on the April 10th New York Times editorial page.
“The Gig Economy’s False Promise” properly debunked what the editorial
board called “the promises Silicon Valley makes about the gig economy,” namely
the illusions of entrepreneurism and independence, and the idea that “use of
the independent contractor model is in fact better for workers.” The problem here is that as an inferior good,
gig jobs, taken mostly when permanent ones are unobtainable, do not hurt those
who have them. As shabby and misleading
as these positions can be, the permanent jobs crisis, not those offering them, deserves
the blame.
Most recent was “Is the gig economy working” (New Yorker, May 15). This long, long form piece (it printed out to
24 pages) used a combination of stories, statistics, and interviews to assess
where this form of work might be going.
Its angle, as its subtitle put it, “many liberals have embraced the
sharing economy. But can they survive
it?”, surprised me, as I had thought of the gig economy as having mostly
conservative appeal, since it facilitates free-market transactions while
requiring workers to defend their own interests without regulatory protection. Author Nathan Heller, though, said some called
it “the power to control one’s working life,” with gigs offering a chance for employment
to “return, grassroots style, to the people.”
He interviewed some who earned money through TaskRabbit and Lyft, who
were actually only choosing the ancient, big-city combination of side work
financing primary efforts in creative projects that may or may not sell, and
contrasted the reality of such jobs with Uber and Airbnb promotional
material. After much more thought,
analysis, and conflation of pure gig opportunities with sharing-economy ones,
he came around to the independent-contracting and health-coverage issues above,
and concluded with a worker, with whom he started the story, finishing a group
of handyman tasks and saying “the gig economy is such a lonely economy.”
No comments:
Post a Comment